Collecting examples to show that “another world is possible.” One way is to
show how much things have changed in history, especially in unexpected ways.
In this interview, Thomas Piketty gives an example from his latest book,
Capital and Ideology of how political and economic inequality in Sweden has
changed dramatically since the turn of the 20th century.
Inequality is a political construction, not the product of “natural” forces
of the economy or technology. Every society needs to tell itself a plausible
story to show why inequalities are acceptable, to justify the organization
of social groups, and to explain the nature of property, borders, the tax
system, and education. Revisiting this story allows us to see our current
ideologies from a different perspective. We often have the impression that
inequalities from the past were necessarily unfair and despotic and that
those of the present are necessarily meritocratic, dynamic, open. I do not
believe a word of it. Macron’s “leaders in the rope line,” the job creators
of Trump, the glorification of fortune whatever its number of zeros: all
this speech is as religious in its way as traditional and explicitly
religious justifications for inequality
History shows that it is impossible to predict the evolution of regimes of
inequality. Take Sweden: we sometimes like to say that the Swedish social
model feeds on a very old culture, going back to the Vikings. In fact,
Sweden was for a long time an extremely unequal country. The census system
until 1911 stipulated that the owners of the biggest fortunes could have up
to one hundred votes per person! Political mobilizations have transformed
the country. If someone had predicted in 1910 that Sweden would become
a social democratic country, nobody would have taken it seriously. That’s
why I do not believe that the current system is indestructible or cannot be
transformed.
I tried to find a source to corroborate this. I found this article in Past
& Present, which I believe is a well-respected academic journal of history.
The Swedish election system was even more unequal on the local level. In the
municipalities, established in 1862, a minimum level of income or wealth was
necessary for the right to vote, and among those with the right to vote, the
number of votes was distributed according to their income and/or wealth. In
urban municipalities, an individual (which could also be a company) could
control up to one hundred votes or 2 per cent of the total votes (5 per cent
before 1869); in rural municipalities, there was no such limit. This
infamously led to several municipalities being ruled by a ‘dictator’ in the
sense that one single individual controlled more than half of the votes. In
1871 this was the case in 54 municipalities, while in 414 localities, more
than a quarter of the votes were controlled by a single individual. In the
1880s, the cousin of the prime minister Count Arvid Posse was one of the
local ‘dictators’, due to the value of his family estate.34 As Mellquist put
it, all countries in Europe restricted the franchise of the poor, but none
were as extreme as the Swedish system.
Two weeks ago, climate activists [celebrated][stopmoney] the news that former
Exxon CEO Lee Raymond would not be returning as Lead Independent Director of
JPMorgan Chase's Board of Directors next term. Lee Raymond has long been vilified by
the environmental movement as one of the key architects of climate denialism
throughout his long career in oil and gas. Although it's unclear to me whether
this change is substantive or decorative (as he still retains his board position
and other board leadership roles, no doubt in great part due to his 33 years of
tenure on the board), activist groups such as the Stop the Money Pipeline
Coalition, touted the victory as a result of "pressur[ing] Wall Street
Institutions to stop financing fossil fuels."
[stopmoney]: https://stopthemoneypipeline.com/raymond-gets-demoted/
This episode highlights the antinomy between the twin tactics of
shareholder activism and divestment campaigns. It seems to me that the
"demotion" of Lee Raymond is more likely due to shareholder activism than
divestment, although it's hard to say what the real causes were. The [_Wall Street
Journal_][wsj], [_Reuters_][reuters], and the [_FT_][ft] all emphasized the
central role of the [New York City pension funds][nyc], holder of 2.4 million
shares, which had launched a campaign to urge other shareholders to vote
against Lee Raymond at the upcoming annual shareholder's meeting. Credit was
also given to Majority Action, a shareholder activism group, which submitted a
[presentation][ma] arguing against Lee Raymond at the upcoming annual
shareholder's meeting.
[nyc]: https://comptroller.nyc.gov/newsroom/comptroller-stringer-and-pension-fund-trustees-launch-vote-no-campaign-against-lee-raymond-at-jpmorgan/
[wsj]: https://www.wsj.com/articles/new-york-city-pension-funds-urge-jpmorgan-shareholders-to-oust-lee-raymond-11587591444
[reuters]: https://www.reuters.com/article/us-jpmorgan-climate-idUSKBN22E00P
[ft]: https://www.ft.com/content/843205f9-6785-4b79-b4be-f1d114b5e826
[ma]: https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/19617/000138713120003979/mja-px14a6g_041720.htm
Let's suppose that it was shareholder activism that led to this outcome. This
mechanism runs directly counter to Stop the Money Pipeline Coalition's
divestment goals. It is precisely because NYC pensions funds and others held
shares of JPMorgan Chase that they were able to exert some influence over the
company, something that wouldn't have happened if [activists have their
way][youth]. In theory, shareholders have a direct, legitimate,
institutionalized process through which they can influence the company, even
as a minority. Divestment involves abdicating those channels of influence in
favor of a vague, financial pressure that only seems to really work once the
vast majority of financial capital participates. Because until then, any
money divested from fossil fuel companies can easily be replaced by new
investment from other neutral investors. Indeed, there are ["vice
funds"][vice] which invest exclusively in companies involved in "sins" such
as alcohol, tobacco, and gambling (but not fossil fuels as far as I can
tell). Such funds would likely see divestment as an opportunity to earn
greater returns.
[youth]: https://insideclimatenews.org/news/14052020/divestment-new-york-pension-plans-fossil-fuels
[vice]: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Vitium_Global_Fund
What, then, is the real impact of divestment campaigns? Do they actually make a
difference? I am no expert on this issue, but I did find an excellent 2013 [report] on
the impact of fossil fuel divestment from Oxford University. The first major
conclusion is that divestment campaigns are unlikely to have any direct
financial impact on fossil fuel companies due to the limited size of outflows
and the likely response from neutral investors who would be happy to pick up new
shares at a discount. In general, a company's market capitalization reflects its
long-term cash flow, which is unaffected by divestment.
[report]: https://ora.ox.ac.uk/objects/uuid:f04181bc-8c4f-4cc1-8f01-cafce57975ae/download_file?file_format=pdf&safe_filename=2013.10.08_SA_in_FF_Div_Campaign.pdf&type_of_work=Report
## Size of Divestment
Let's get a sense of the numbers. A 2014 [Bloomberg report] stated that the
market value of the 1,744 publicly listed oil, gas, and coal companies were
collectively worth $4.88 trillion. The [Fossil Free] movement currently reports
divestment commitments from institutions managing a total of $14.14 trillion.
But that number is not representative of actual divestment.
First, it represents the total value of all investments managed by those
institutions, not the value of fossil fuel investments. The Oxford report
states that endowments and pension funds invest about 2-5% in fossil fuel
related equities and about half of that in fossil fuel related debt. For
instance, US university endowments have 2% of assets committed to fossil fuel
equities, whereas the CalPERS, the California state pension fund, in 2012 had
5.2% in fossil fuel equities. So if we take an average of 3.5%, then those
$14.14 trillion of commitments translates into $495 billion, or just over 10%
of the total market value of the fossil fuel industry. That's certainly quite an
achievement, but probably still not big enough to make a big dent.
Second, the actual amount of money divested is lower than the $495 billion we
just calculated, because many institutions are only partially divesting. Several
institutions are only divested from companies involved in coal or tar sands, often considered to be the
most environmentally harmful. The Bloomberg report stated that coal firms make
up less than 5% of the total fossil fuel industry, meaning that divestment only
from coal is only a tiny step toward full divestment. However, it seems that
only 96 of the 1198 institutions tracked by [Fossil Free] are committing to
coal or tar sands only, suggesting that the vast majority of institutions are going further.
[Fossil Free]: https://gofossilfree.org/divestment/commitments/
It's also worth noting that most of these institutions have only committed to
divestment, but may not have actually gone through with them yet. Fossil Free
[distinguishes] between institutions that have made a binding commitment to
divestment and those that actual have zero investments. Only 58 are currently
categorized as totally fossil free, whereas another 920 institutions are
classified as having made a binding commitment toward full divestment. Granted,
it is likely that many of these institutions are already fully divested, but
just have not announced it.
[distinguishes]: https://gofossilfree.org/divestment-commitments-classifications/
[Bloomberg report]: https://data.bloomberglp.com/bnef/sites/4/2014/08/BNEF_DOC_2014-08-25-Fossil-Fuel-Divestment.pdf
## Indirect Effects of Divestment
In any case, the Oxford report states that the real impact of divestment
campaigns comes from indirect social and political effects. The bottom line is
that anything that can affect expectations around future cash flows would have a
durable effect on equity prices and interest rates for fossil fuel companies.
Divestment would have little effect on this, unless so much of the market
becomes antagonistic to fossil fuel companies that their cost of capital
increases. (The Oxford reports note that this is more likely to happen for
coal companies and companies in countries with lower availability of debt
financing.)
The first mechanism of indirect impact is stigmatization, whereby customers,
employees, suppliers, and others opt not to do business with a firm for
non-economic reasons. While I can see how this mechanism functions for
consumer-facing companies and even B2B or B2G companies, I have a hard time
envisioning how this would function for oil and gas companies, who seem so
many layers removed from most people's decision-making but also deeply woven into
our lives and thus difficult to excise. Perhaps another challenge is that oil
and gas are commodities, which aren't subject to the risks or benefits of a
brand (with the exception of gas stations). The Oxford report is not
much help, as its examples of stigmatization, such as Motorola's divestment from
its defense business and Revlon's divestment from its South Africa operations,
are for consumer-facing businesses. The report does note that the Exxon Valdez
and Deepwater Horizon oil spills triggered some changes, but I don't think that
these are the right examples to use for stigmatization, as they were the result
of acute disasters followed by investigations and litigation, rather than the
accumulation of stigmatization through sustained campaigning.
The second mechanism of indirect impact is through the threat of restrictive
legislation, such as a carbon tax or tightened regulations. The Oxford report
points out that such legislation does not even need to be enacted to have an
impact, as the mere increased probability of such legislation is enough to
reduce expectations about future oil and gas revenues, or at least increase
their uncertainty. The report states that past divestment campaigns have
often been successful in lobbying for restrictive legislation. While there's no
doubt that divestment can only help the cause for restrictive legislation, it's
unclear how effective they were compared to other parallel campaigns. For
instance, the only concrete example given in the Oxford report is
the Public Health Cigarette Smoking Act of 1970, which is frequently attributed
to the 1964 Surgeon General report on the health effects of tobacco. Health
research played a clear role, but it's unclear what role divestment campaigns
in particular played in generating the political pressure to legislation.
I would add a third mechanism of indirect impact left undiscussed in the Oxford
report. Fossil fuel campaigns may have been one of the more effective
vehicles for getting people involved in climate issues and climate activism. It
might be one of the main ways that many college students in particular learn
about climate impacts and start thinking about climate solutions. Divestment
campaigns benefit from a simple narrative ("stop funding destruction") and
political battlegrounds located at universities. Endowments and
pension funds are good political targets, because they are large enough to
generate the excitement of an audacious goal, not as politicized as
legislative politics, and they have the spirit of serving a group of
people, even if there may not always be a formal mechanism for democratic
influence. Because the impacts of climate change are so diffuse and
probabilistic, it can be quite hard to generate political energy and activism.
Divestment campaigns might be one of the most effective ways to frame the
climate crisis in a way that gets people energized to fight rather than feel
overwhelmed. Political narratives need an enemy, and fossil fuel corporations
and their financiers can play that role, even as we are also complicit in our
fossil fueled lifestyles.
All this suggests that if you are an individual in control of
personal or institutional funds, simply divesting from fossil fuels
won't make any difference unless you tell other people. Ironically, as a
institutional fund manager, you might have a larger impact by dragging out the
divestment process in a way that allows the divestment movement to grow and
achieve milestones at regular intervals so that they feel empowered and
encouraged. Giving into divestment too quickly could collapse your local
divestment campaign, which may be serving as a crucial organization that
provides political training and experience to its members and climate
communication to the broader community. Perhaps we should start a covert
campaign to get institutional fund managers to divest, but slowly!
Majority Action's [submission][ma] for the JPMorgan Chase annual shareholder meeting
(to be held May 19, 2020) titled "Vote AGAINST Lee Raymond For Independent and
Climate Competent Governance at JPMorgan Chase (JPM)." The first time I've
personally seen a sample of shareholder activism, something I've learned a bit
about in the last couple days.
[ma]: https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/19617/000138713120003979/mja-px14a6g_041720.htm
Fantastic [report][divest] from Oxford from 2013 on the impact of fossil fuel
divestment, for being extremely informative, clearly presented, and combining
financial and sociological insights into markets. In short, direct impacts from
divestment campaigns (i.e., literal money divested) is probably minimal, but
indirect effects of stigmatization and increased likelihood of restrictive
legislation can lead to increased uncertainty of future cash flows which can
cause greater financial impact.
[divest]: https://ora.ox.ac.uk/objects/uuid:f04181bc-8c4f-4cc1-8f01-cafce57975ae/download_file?file_format=pdf&safe_filename=2013.10.08_SA_in_FF_Div_Campaign.pdf&type_of_work=Report
Short (13-page) [pitch][cfad] on carbon fee and dividend by James Hansen and Daniel
Miller, presented for the House of Representatives in November 2019.
[cfad]: https://drive.google.com/file/d/14XypWkRWvX8CDPAPUBC3g28oDMo9ijXz/view
Good overview in [NYRB][biomass] on context around use of biomass for
electricity. I suppose it serves as a case of how legislation and regulations
that are environmental and sustainable in name can contain loopholes and
exceptions that lead to environmentally destructive outcomes. Another example
would be the exempting of fracking fluids from multiple environmental protection
laws in the [2005 Energy Policy
Act](https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Energy_Policy_Act_of_2005).
[biomass]: https://www.nybooks.com/daily/2019/10/14/the-great-biomass-boondoggle/
Great [powerpoint][ubi] from _interfluidity_, a blog I've only just recently
discovered, on the benefits of UBI from a highly economistic perspective.
[ubi]: https://www.interfluidity.com/uploads/2015/09/ethereumsv-ubi-talk-light-reedit.pdf
[Wikipedia's Lamest Edit Wars](https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:Lamest_edit_wars)
Change begins at home. Having come home due to coronavirus, I figured it was
time to look at my home's energy usage and its emissions. For context, I'm
currently staying in a 1500 sq ft townhouse in the SF Bay Area with two
occupants. Based on our utility bills from the last four years, we've used an
average of 175 kWh of electricity and 14.5 therms of natural gas per month.
## How do we compare to the average?
The US Energy Information Administration (EIA) occasionally conducts a
Residential Energy Consumption Survey (RECS) household energy usage patterns.
The [most recent RECS][recs2015] is from 2015, for which they sampled 5,600
households out of the 118.2 million households in the US.
[recs2015]: https://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/data/2015/
Based on the 2015 RECS, the average household in the US
[consumes][recs2015avgus] 893 kWh of electricity and 48 therms of natural gas
per month. Apparently, our household footprint is far lower than the national
average: one-fifth of the electricity and one-third of the natural gas!
That's good, but that's quite an easy bar to beat, given that:
1. Our house's square footage (1500 sq ft) is 25% lower than the [national
average][recs2015sqft] of 2008 sq ft.
2. Our household size or occupancy (~0.9 due to travel) is much lower than
the [average household size][census-household-size] of 2.5.
3. California households [use 31% less energy][eia-ca-brief] than the US
average, among the lowest in the nation. One big reason is that California's
mild climate reduces the need for heating and air conditioning.
On top of this, beating the US average isn't something to be proud of, as
the average American uses [more than double][eia-energy-consumption] the
energy of the average European, and nearly four times as much
energy as the average person on earth. And one big reason is that Americans love
big houses, and space heating and air conditioning use a lot of energy.
[recs2015avgus]: https://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/data/2015/c&e/pdf/ce4.6.pdf
[recs2015sqft]: https://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/data/2015/hc/php/hc10.9.php
[census-household-size]: https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/visualizations/time-series/demo/families-and-households/hh-6.pdf
[eia-ca-brief]: https://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/reports/2009/state_briefs/pdf/ca.pdf
[eia-ca-analysis]: https://www.eia.gov/state/analysis.php?sid=CA#4
[eia-energy-consumption]: https://www.eia.gov/international/data/world/total-energy/total-energy-consumption?pd=44&p=000000001&u=0&f=A&v=mapbubble&a=-&i=none&vo=value&&t=G&g=none&l=249-00000000000000000000000000000000000000000000000201&l=71--71&l=170--170&s=315532800000&e=1483228800000
Nonetheless, PG&E, our regional utility company, tells me that our household
still has lower energy usage than other houses in our neighborhood.
That's certainly a good thing, but much of the different must be due to the
fact that the occupancy in our home is much lower than other homes here.
## Emissions
PG&E reports that in 2018 their CO2 emissions rate was only [93 grams of CO2 per
kWh][pge-footprint] of electricity generated. I found this astounding, as the
[national average][eia-elec-footprint] is 449 grams of CO2 per kWh! It appears
that [PG&E generates][pge-power-mix] 69% of its electricity from nuclear and
renewables, 17% from natural gas, and none from coal or oil (the dirtiest
sources). The remaining 14% is marked as "unspecified," meaning it
cannot be traced to its source. That's intriguing. Based on this figure, our
household emissions from electricity amount to 0.54kg CO2/day or 195.3kg CO2/year.
[pge-footprint]: https://www.pge.com/en_US/about-pge/environment/what-we-are-doing/fighting-climate-change/fighting-climate-change.page
[eia-elec-footprint]: https://www.eia.gov/tools/faqs/faq.php?id=74&t=11
[pge-power-mix]: https://www.pge.com/pge_global/local/assets/data/en-us/your-account/your-bill/understand-your-bill/bill-inserts/2017/november/power-content.pdf
The [EPA reports][epa-equiv] that burning one therm of natural gas releases
5.3kg of CO2. Thus our household gas usage results in 2.56kg CO2/day or 922.2kg
CO2/year, bringing our total emissions to 3.1kg CO2/day or 1,117.5kg CO2/year.
[epa-equiv]: https://www.epa.gov/energy/greenhouse-gases-equivalencies-calculator-calculations-and-references
For comparison, the average American [emits about 17 tons][wb] of CO2 per year (not
including other greenhouse gases, such as methane) of which [6.1 tons][kalmus] come from
electricity and natural gas. Europeans emit about 8 tons in total per year and
the global average is about 5 tons.
The most interesting result here is that natural gas makes up 82.5% of our
household emissions! The fact that PG&E generates most of its electricity from
nuclear and renewables means that our natural gas usage has an outsized
carbon footprint.
[wb]: https://databank.worldbank.org/reports.aspx?source=2&series=EN.ATM.CO2E.PC&country=
[kalmus]: https://peterkalmus.net/books/read-by-chapter-being-the-change/read-by-chapter-chapter-9-leaving-fossil-fuel/
## Reducing our footprint
If we wanted to reduce the carbon footprint of our home, it seems the most
effective solution would be to switch our heating sources (central heating,
water heating, and stove) to electric alternatives. However, most people prefer
gas heating because it's considered to be cheaper to operate. What would the
cost difference be for us, with PG&E?
For the sake of simplicity, let's just assume all the natural gas we currently
use is for central heating. We currently use an average of 14.5 therms of
natural gas per month. One therm contains 29.3 kWh of power, so that comes out
to 5098 kWh of energy per year. Compare that to 2100 kWh of electricity that we
use per year. Our [central heating furnace][58ctw] has a annual fuel-utilization
efficiency (AFUE) of 80%, basically meaning that it's 80% of the 5098 kWh of
energy contained in the natural gas is actually being converted into heat. In
contrast, electric furnaces have higher efficiency, as high as 100%.
We currently pay $0.24/kWh for electricity and $1.41/therm for natural gas. Over
the course of a year, the $245 we currently pay for natural gas would be
replaced by a $988 bill for the added electricity. In reality, the bill would
likely be more than that, due to the fact that the rate of electricity
increases to $0.30/kWh when we cross a baseline threshold that we currently do
not cross but would likely be crossed on days we use central heating. The
exact numbers will depend on a variety of factors, but the overall
point is that the cost of heating would roughly quadruple from switching to
electricity.
[58ctw]: https://www.carrier.com/residential/en/us/products/gas-furnaces/58ctw/
Of course, there are many other ways to reduce our overall carbon footprint
significantly without having to pay more. Reducing flying, eating less meat and
dairy, and driving less would all have a substantial impact on our carbon
footprint. In particular, for those of us who do fly more than a few times a
year, flying is likely to make up the majority of our individual carbon emissions.
While reading Tania Murray Li's book [_The Will To Improve_][will], I came
across an interesting quote.
[will]: https://www.dukeupress.edu/The-Will-to-Improve/
> A third dimension to improvement might also be labeled antipolitics: the
> design of programs as a deliberate measure to contain a challenge to the
> status quo. In Britain in 1847, for example, an observer argued for special
> programs for paupers because they were "the class of men injured by society
> who consequently rebel against it." Another argued, "Assisting the poor
> is a means of government, a potent way of containing the most difficult section
> of the population and improving all the other sections." (p. 8)
I found this quote interesting because for some time I've been interested in
collecting concrete examples and primary source material that provide insight
into how the "ruling class" thinks and what they believe. A range of political discourses
make frequent reference to some notion of a ruling elite, whether that's the
capitalist class (Marxists), the 1% (Bernie and Occupy), or the deep state
(Trump). There is some truth to some versions of this, especially in America,
where I live. Indeed, I often think of [Gilen & Page 2014][gp14], which
showed that "economic elites and organized groups representing business
interests have substantial independent impacts on U.S. government policy,
while average citizens and mass-based interest groups have little or no
independent influence."
[gp14]: https://scholar.princeton.edu/sites/default/files/mgilens/files/gilens_and_page_2014_-testing_theories_of_american_politics.doc.pdf
But I have many issues with the simplistic way in which the ruling elite is
often described as a monolithic, prescient, competent cabal which consistently
and skillfully acts in their own interests.
1. The ruling elite is not a monolithic group, and will oftentimes be
uncoordinated, have divergent interests, and have disagreements.
2. Many political and economic outcomes that benefit the ruling elite may not be
the result of intentional action, but could be the result of happenstance or
an emergent structural outcome—the result of many interacting forces,
interests, institutions, etc. rather than any single will or vision.
3. The ruling elite cannot always be perceiving the present state of affairs or
anticipating the future with perfect clarity.
4. Even when the ruling elite has clear foresight (e.g., anticipating that the
current state of affairs will lead to social unrest), they may not arrive at
the right or best course of action in their own interests.
5. Even if the ruling elite decides to undertake the right actions (for their
own interests), they may have the capacity or the competence to implement it
successfully.
The debacle that has been the American government response to the coronavirus
pandemic (as well as many other government responses) is one case to consider
when thinking about the ability of the ruling elite to act in their own
interests. With the benefit of hindsight, we can see that an earlier and more
aggressive response to the coronavirus would have benefited the ruling class
both economically and politically. However, they failed to act accordingly. Of
course, they are taking the opportunity of the crisis to benefit themselves in
various ways, such as rolling back environmental regulations or bailing out
corporations. But it's unclear to me whether these outweigh the general economic
losses suffered from a disastrous government response. It's even less clear to
me that the elite would think about this tradeoff and deliberately choose to
delay the pandemic response in order to capitalize upon a partially manufactured
crisis.
Anyway, back to the original quote from Li. I was excited by this quote because
it provided concrete examples with direct quotes showing how the ruling elite
thought about welfare in terms of social control (i.e., framed in terms of
elite interests) rather than magnanimity. I was reminded of the Marxist
perspective on state welfare, which cynically views welfare programs as a tool
of social control and of maintaining capitalist exploitation. In the Marxist
view, state welfare is a perfect example of how (a) the state acts in capitalist
interests and (b) the capitalists are able to act in their own interests as a
_class_, and not just individually. State welfare pacifies the working
classes by preventing those extreme forms of wretched indigence that can lead to
social unrest and disorder. Healthcare and education also provides for a
productive labor supply. In other words, the welfare system helps fine-tune the
optimal degree of exploitation and maintain the status quo. As Georg Simmel puts
it,
> The goal of assistance is precisely to mitigate certain extreme
> manifestations of social differentiation, so that the social structure may
> continue to be based on this differentiation.
So, I thought that I'd dig a bit deeper into the context behind these quotes, to
get a sense of the degree to which it was representative of elite views at the
time. Both quotes were quoted in the essay "Social Economy and the Government of
Poverty" by Giovanna Procacci, published in _The Foucault Effect_, a collection
of essays on the Foucauldian concept of governmentality.
The first quote is originally from a 1847 French book titled _Du progrès
social au profit des classes populaires non indigentes_ by a French
politician named Francois Félix de Lafarelle, a man important enough to have
a [French wikipedia entry][wiki] but not an English one. Li ascribes this
quote to an observer in Britain in 1847, but Procacci gives no such context.
In fact, Procacci uses the quote without any context at all, using it as one
of three quotes to make a point about how the discourse of the time frames
"pauperism" as a "social danger" distinct from poverty that must be
eradicated lest the social order be threatened or perverted. I found it
suspicious that a French politician writing a book in French would be
commenting on British social policy, and the lack of any context given by
Procacci did not help. Amazingly, I found a [scanned copy][archive] of the
book on Archive.org, which makes me all the more impressed and grateful for
their work. I even found a copy of the book for sale on [Amazon][amazon].
Procacci cited the quote from page 7, but I could find nothing on that page
that matched what Procacci had written. It appeared to be a discussion of
Adam Smith, but without any reference to contemporary British policy. I was also
disappointed that Procacci did not mention that the quote was translated.
This first quote felt like sloppy referencing on the parts of both Li and
Procacci. Disappointing.
[wiki]: https://fr.wikipedia.org/wiki/F%C3%A9lix_de_Lafarelle
[amazon]: https://www.amazon.com/Progr%C3%A9s-Social-Classes-Populaires-Indigentes/dp/1149835133
[archive]: https://archive.org/details/duprogrssociala01faregoog/page/n27/mode/2up
The second quote is actually the epigraph to Procacci's essay, and similarly is
not given any context or explanation. It is attributed to Firmin Marbeau's book
_Du paupérisme en France et des moyens d'y remédier ou principes d'economie
charitable_, also published in 1847. Unfortunately Procacci provided no page
number, so even though I managed to find a [scanned copy][bnf] from the
Bibliothèque Nationale de France (National Library of France), there's no way I
would be able to verify the reference. At least the title of the book indicates
it's on the right topic. But another dead end.
[bnf]: https://gallica.bnf.fr/ark:/12148/bpt6k842422/f1.image
This was a disappointing exercise. A perennial but empirically intractable
question that arises in politics and sociology is whether politicians and other
elites really believe the things that they say. Did they really believe in
trickle-down economics, reducing the government deficit, or austerity, or was it
just an ideological cloak for policies they knew would ultimately benefit the
ruling class? Obviously some really believe what they say and others don't, but
unfortunately the evidence to show who really believes what is hard to come by.
That's why I was excited to dig into these quotes, even though they were about a
different (but closely related) country 170 years ago. But I ended up uncovering
some slipshod work.
I'm not disappointed because I didn't find what I wanted. I'm disappointed
because my estimation of the quality of these works and their authors has
diminished significantly. If these two references turned out to be of such
poor quality, what I am to think of other references, or the authors' rigor
and attention to detail? I also worry that the reviewers and editors did not
catch this, and I worry that this is more broadly indicative of relatively poorer
academic rigor in this area of academic writing, which already gets mocked by
the more analytical and quantitative spheres of social studies. Alas, I know
not to excessively generalize. I remain disappointed.